Turning Down the Heat

Turning Down the Heat

In the global warming debate, both sides are right: the Kyoto treaty has flaws, but greenhouse emissions are real, and causing verifiable effects. One longtime observer believes it's time to do something about them.

Share:
Read Time:
2m 54sec

The source:“Case Closed: The Debate About Global Warming Is Over” by Gregg Easterbrook, in Issues in Governance Studies (June 2006).

The global warming debate is gridlocked in part because the problem seems almost too big and costly to solve. That’s foolish, argues Gregg Easterbrook: “Greenhouse gases are an air pollution problem, and all air pollution problems of the past have cost significantly less to fix than projected, while declining faster than expected.”

Easterbrook, a visiting fellow at the Brookings Institution, detailed that history in his 1995 book A Moment on the Earth. He also criticized environmentalists (with whom he was sympathetic) for inducing gloom about what could be accomplished in the future by ignoring the great gains America had already made in reducing pollution. At the time, he was somewhat skeptical of claims about hu­man-caused global warming, but no longer. The ques­tion now is what to do about it.

Critics of the Kyoto Protocol, ratified by more than 160 coun­tries but not the United States, are right, Easterbrook says. Even if the treaty were perfectly enforced, “atmos­pheric concentrations of greenhouse gases in 2050 would be only about one percent less than without the treaty.” (The Bush administration’s unsung multinational methane reduction pact of 2003, Easter­brook adds, “may do more to slow global warming than perfect com­pliance with the Kyoto treaty.”) And perfect compliance is a pipe dream: “Most nations that have ratified the Kyoto treaty are merrily ignoring it.” Canada’s greenhouse gas emissions are 24 percent above the ­Kyoto-­man­dated ­level, for instance.

Easterbrook’s optimism comes from U.S. experience in reducing ordinary air pollution during the past 30 years. “Today, any make or model new car purchased in the United States emits about one percent the amount of ­smog-­forming compounds per mile as a car of 1970, and the cost of the ­anti­-smog technology is less than $100 per vehicle.” Remember acid rain? After Congress enacted an emissions permit trading plan in 1991, the output of harmful sulfur compounds dropped by more than a third, and “Appal­ach­ian forests are currently in their best health since Europeans first laid eyes on them.” The reductions cost only $200 per ton of emissions cut, not the $2,000 originally ­projected.

The lesson: “Create a profit incentive for greenhouse gas reduction, and human ingenuity will rapidly be applied to the problem.” That means eschewing detailed government regulation and creating “a ­market-­based system of auctioned or traded greenhouse gas permits.” Major emitters of gases such as carbon dioxide would be issued permits allowing them to release certain quantities of the gases. If they produced less, they would be entitled to sell leftover permits to producers who emitted more than their quota. Everybody would have a strong financial incentive to reduce ­emissions.

That would speed the adoption of new technologies, from the familiar wind and solar power alter­natives to the less known. General Electric, for example, has developed ­coal-­fired power plants that emit no greenhouse gases. More important, such incentives would unleash the human power of invention, with results we can’t even imagine ­now.

What about the developing world, with its soaring output of greenhouse gases? In a global system that gave credits for cutting emissions in places such as China, where old and antiquated technologies could be quickly updated, the gains could be ­huge.

The United States led the world in finding ways to tame smog and acid rain, Easterbrook declares, “and we should be first to overcome global warming.”

More From This Issue